Economics of climate change mitigation
This article's lead section may be too short to adequately summarize the key points. (November 2020) |
Part of a series on |
Economics |
---|
The economics of climate change mitigation is a contentious part of climate change mitigation – action aimed to limit the dangerous socio-economic and environmental consequences of climate change.[4]
Climate change mitigation centres on two main strategies: the reduction of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and the preservation and expansion of sinks which absorb greenhouse gases, including the sea and forests.
The economics of climate change mitigation are a central point of contention whose considerations significantly affect the level of climate action at every level from local to global.
For example, higher interest rates are slowing solar panel installation in developing countries.[5]
Policies and approaches to reduce emissions
[edit]Price signals
[edit]A carbon price is a system of applying a price to carbon emissions, as a method of emissions mitigation.[6] Potential methods of pricing include carbon emission trading, results-based climate finance, crediting mechanisms and more.[7] Carbon pricing can lend itself to the creation of carbon taxes, which allows governments to tax emissions.[6]
Carbon taxes are considered useful because, once a number[clarification needed] has been created, it will benefit the government either with currency or with a lowering in emissions or both, and therefore benefit the environment.[8] It is almost a consensus that carbon taxing is the most cost-effective method of having a substantial and rapid response to climate change and carbon emissions.[9] However, backlash to the tax includes that it can be considered regressive, as the impact can be damaging disproportionately to the poor who spend much of their income on energy for their homes.[10] Still, even with near universal approval, there are issues regarding both the collection and redistribution of the taxes. One of the central questions being how the newly collected taxes will be redistributed.[11]
Some or all of the proceeds of a carbon tax can be used to stop it disadvantaging the poor.[12]
Structural market reforms
[edit]In addition to the implementation of command-and-control regulations (as with a carbon tax), governments can also use market-based approaches to mitigate emissions. One such method is emissions trading where governments set the total emissions of all polluters to a maximum and distribute permits, through auction or allocation, that allow entities to emit a portion, typically one ton of carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e), of the mandated total emissions.[13] In other words, the amount of pollution an entity can emit in an emissions trading system is limited by the number of permits they have. If a polluter wants to increase their emissions, they can only do so after buying permits from those who are willing to sell them.[14] Many economists prefer this method of reducing emissions as it is market based and highly cost effective.[13] That being said, emissions trading alone is not perfect since it fails to place a clear price on emissions. Without this price, emissions prices are volatile due to the supply of permits being fixed, meaning their price is entirely determined by shifts in demand.[15] This uncertainty in price is especially disliked by businesses since it prevents them from investing in abatement technologies with confidence which hinders efforts for mitigating emissions.[15] Regardless, while emissions trading alone has its problems and cannot reduce pollutants to the point of stabilizing the global climate, it remains an important tool for addressing climate change.
Degrowth
[edit]There is a debate about a potentially critical need for new ways of economic accounting, including directly monitoring and quantifying positive real-world environmental effects such as air quality improvements and related unprofitable work like forest protection, alongside far-reaching structural changes of lifestyles[16][17] as well as acknowledging and moving beyond the limits of current economics such as GDP.[18] Some argue that for effective climate change mitigation degrowth has to occur, while some argue that eco-economic decoupling could limit climate change enough while continuing high rates of traditional GDP growth.[19][20] There is also research and debate about requirements of how economic systems could be transformed for sustainability – such as how their jobs could transition harmonously into green jobs – a just transition – and how relevant sectors of the economy – like the renewable energy industry and the bioeconomy – could be adequately supported.[21][22]
While degrowth is often believed to be associated with decreased living standards and austerity measures, many of its proponents seek to expand universal public goods[23][24] (such as public transport), increase health[25][26][27] (fitness, wellbeing[28] and freedom from diseases) and increase various forms of, often unconventional commons-oriented,[29] labor. To this end, the application of both advanced technologies and reductions in various demands, including via overall reduced labor time[30] or sufficiency-oriented strategies,[31] are considered to be important by some.[32][33]
Finance
[edit]There are two main sub-categories of climate finance based on different aims. Mitigation finance is investment that aims to reduce global carbon emissions. Adaptation finance aims to respond to the consequences of climate change.[36] Globally, there is a much greater focus on mitigation, accounting for over 90% of spending on climate.[37][38]: 2590 Renewable energy is an important growth area for mitigation investment and has growing policy support.[39]: 5
Finance can come from private and public sources, and sometimes the two can intersect to create financial solutions. It is widely recognized that public budgets will be insufficient to meet the total needs for climate finance, and that private finance will be important to close the finance gap.[40]: 16 Many different financial models or instruments have been used for financing climate actions. For example green bonds, carbon offsetting, and payment for ecosystem services are some promoted solutions. There is considerable innovation in this area. Transfer of solutions that were not developed specifically for climate finance is also taking place, such as public–private partnerships and blended finance.
There are many challenges with climate finance. Firstly, there are difficulties with measuring and tracking financial flows. Secondly, there are also questions around equitable financial support to developing countries for cutting emissions and adapting to impacts. It is also difficult to provide suitable incentives for investments from the private sector.Assessing costs and benefits
[edit]GDP
[edit]The costs of mitigation and adaptation policies can be measured as a percentage of GDP. A problem with this method of assessing costs is that GDP is an imperfect measure of welfare.[41]: 478 There are externalities in the economy which mean that some prices might not be truly reflective of their social costs.
Corrections can be made to GDP estimates to allow for these problems, but they are difficult to calculate. In response to this problem, some have suggested using other methods to assess policy. For example, the United Nations Commission for Sustainable Development has developed a system for "Green" GDP accounting and a list of sustainable development indicators.
Baselines
[edit]The emissions baseline is, by definition, the emissions that would occur in the absence of policy intervention. Definition of the baseline scenario is critical in the assessment of mitigation costs.[41]: 469 This because the baseline determines the potential for emissions reductions, and the costs of implementing emission reduction policies.
There are several concepts used in the literature over baselines, including the "efficient" and "business-as-usual" (BAU) baseline cases. In the efficient baseline, it is assumed that all resources are being employed efficiently. In the BAU case, it is assumed that future development trends follow those of the past, and no changes in policies will take place. The BAU baseline is often associated with high GHG emissions, and may reflect the continuation of current energy-subsidy policies, or other market failures.
Some high emission BAU baselines imply relatively low net mitigation costs per unit of emissions. If the BAU scenario projects a large growth in emissions, total mitigation costs can be relatively high. Conversely, in an efficient baseline, mitigation costs per unit of emissions can be relatively high, but total mitigation costs low.[clarification needed]
Ancillary impacts
[edit]These are the secondary or side effects of mitigation policies, and including them in studies can result in higher or lower mitigation cost estimates.[41]: 455 Reduced mortality and morbidity costs are potentially a major ancillary benefit of mitigation. This benefit is associated with reduced use of fossil fuels, thereby resulting in less air pollution, which might even just by itself be a benefit greater than the cost.[42]: 48 There may also be ancillary costs.
Flexibility
[edit]Flexibility is the ability to reduce emissions at the lowest cost. The greater the flexibility that governments allow in their regulatory framework to reduce emissions, the lower the potential costs are for achieving emissions reductions (Markandya et al., 2001:455).[41]
- "Where" flexibility allows costs to be reduced by allowing emissions to be cut at locations where it is most efficient to do so. For example, the Flexibility Mechanisms of the Kyoto Protocol allow "where" flexibility (Toth et al., 2001:660).[43]
- "When" flexibility potentially lowers costs by allowing reductions to be made at a time when it is most efficient to do so.
Including carbon sinks in a policy framework is another source of flexibility. Tree planting and forestry management actions can increase the capacity of sinks. Soils and other types of vegetation are also potential sinks. There is, however, uncertainty over how net emissions are affected by activities in this area.[41][clarification needed]
No regrets options
[edit]This section may be too technical for most readers to understand.(November 2019) |
No regret options are social and economic benefits developed under the assumption of taking action and establishing preventative measures in current times without fully knowing what climate change will look like in the future.[44][45]
These are emission reduction options which can also make a lot of profit – such as adding solar and wind power.[46]: TS-108
Different studies make different assumptions about how far the economy is from the production frontier (defined as the maximum outputs attainable with the optimal use of available inputs – natural resources, labour, etc.).[47]
The benefits of coal phase out exceed the costs.[48] Switching from cars by improving walking and cycling infrastructure is either free or beneficial to a country's economy as a whole.[49]
Technology
[edit]Assumptions about technological development and efficiency in the baseline and mitigation scenarios have a major impact on mitigation costs, in particular in bottom-up studies.[41] The magnitude of potential technological efficiency improvements depends on assumptions about future technological innovation and market penetration rates for these technologies.
Discount rates
[edit]Assessing climate change impacts and mitigation policies involves a comparison of economic flows that occur in different points in time. The discount rate is used by economists to compare economic effects occurring at different times. Discounting converts future economic impacts into their present-day value. The discount rate is generally positive because resources invested today can, on average, be transformed into more resources later. If climate change mitigation is viewed as an investment, then the return on investment can be used to decide how much should be spent on mitigation.
Integrated assessment models (IAM) are used to estimate the social cost of carbon. The discount rate is one of the factors used in these models. The IAM frequently used is the Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy (DICE) model developed by William Nordhaus. The DICE model uses discount rates, uncertainty, and risks to make benefit and cost estimations of climate policies and adapt to the current economic behavior.[50]
The choice of discount rate has a large effect on the result of any climate change cost analysis (Halsnæs et al., 2007:136).[51] Using too high a discount rate will result in too little investment in mitigation, but using too low a rate will result in too much investment in mitigation. In other words, a high discount rate implies that the present-value of a dollar is worth more than the future-value of a dollar.
Discounting can either be prescriptive or descriptive. The descriptive approach is based on what discount rates are observed in the behaviour of people making every day decisions (the private discount rate) (IPCC, 2007c:813).[47] In the prescriptive approach, a discount rate is chosen based on what is thought to be in the best interests of future generations (the social discount rate).
The descriptive approach can be interpreted[clarification needed] as an effort to maximize the economic resources available to future generations, allowing them to decide how to use those resources (Arrow et al., 1996b:133–134).[52] The prescriptive approach can be interpreted as an effort to do as much as is economically justified[clarification needed] to reduce the risk of climate change.
The DICE model incorporates a descriptive approach, in which discounting reflects actual economic conditions. In a recent[when?] DICE model, DICE-2013R Model, the social cost of carbon is estimated based on the following alternative scenarios: (1) a baseline scenario, when climate change policies have not changed since 2010, (2) an optimal scenario, when climate change policies are optimal (fully implemented and followed), (3) when the optimal scenario does not exceed 2˚C limit after 1900 data, (4) when the 2˚C limit is an average and not the optimum, (5) when a near-zero (low) discount rate of 0.1% is used (as assumed in the Stern Review), (6) when a near-zero discount rate is also used but with calibrated interest rates, and (7) when a high discount rate of 3.5% is used.[53][needs update]
According to Markandya et al. (2001:466), discount rates used in assessing mitigation programmes need to at least partly reflect the opportunity costs of capital.[41] In developed countries, Markandya et al. (2001:466) thought that a discount rate of around 4–6% was probably justified, while in developing countries, a rate of 10–12% was cited. The discount rates used in assessing private projects were found to be higher – with potential rates of between 10% and 25%.
When deciding how to discount future climate change impacts, value judgements are necessary (Arrow et al., 1996b:130). IPCC (2001a:9) found that there was no consensus on the use of long-term discount rates in this area.[54] The prescriptive approach to discounting leads to long-term discount rates of 2–3% in real terms, while the descriptive approach leads to rates of at least 4% after tax – sometimes much higher (Halsnæs et al., 2007:136).
Even today, it is difficult to agree on an appropriate discount rate. The approach of discounting to be either prescriptive or descriptive stemmed from the views of Nordhaus and Stern. Nordhaus takes on a descriptive approach which "assumes that investments to slow climate change must compete with investments in other areas". While Stern takes on a prescriptive approach in which "leads to the conclusion that any positive pure rate of time preference is unethical".[50]
In Nordhaus' view, his descriptive approach translates that the impact of climate change is slow, thus investments in climate change should be on the same level of competition with other investments. He defines the discount rate to be the rate of return on capital investments. The DICE model uses the estimated market return on capital as the discount rate, around an average of 4%. He argues that a higher discount rate will make future damages look small, thus have less effort to reduce emissions today. A lower discount rate will make future damages look larger, thus put more effort to reduce emissions today.[55]
In Stern's view, the pure rate of time preference is defined as the discount rate in a scenario where present and future generations have equal resources and opportunities.[56] A zero pure rate of time preference in this case would indicate that all generations are treated equally. The future generation do not have a "voice" on today's current policies, so the present generation are morally responsible to treat the future generation in the same manner. He suggests for a lower discount rate in which the present generation should invest in the future to reduce the risks of climate change.
Assumptions are made to support estimating high and low discount rates. These estimates depend on future emissions, climate sensitivity relative to increase in greenhouse gas concentrations, and the seriousness of impacts over time.[57] Long-term climate policies will significantly impact future generations and this is called intergenerational discounting. Factors that make intergenerational discounting complicated include the great uncertainty of economic growth, future generations are affected by today's policies, and private discounting will be affected due to a longer "investment horizon".[58]
Controversy
[edit]Discounting is a relatively controversial issue in both climate change mitigation and environmental economics due to the ethical implications of valuing future generations less than present ones. Non-economists often find it difficult to grapple with the idea that thousands of dollars of future costs and benefits can be valued at less than a cent in the present after discounting.[59] This devaluation can lead to overconsumption and "strategic ignorance" where individuals choose to ignore information that would prevent the overconsumption of resources.[60] Contrary to this, orthodox economists concerned with equality argue that it is important to distribute society's resources equitably across time, and since they generally, rightly or wrongly predict positive economic growth, despite global climate change, they argue that current generations should damage the environment in which future generations live so that the current ones can consume and produce more to equalize the (rightly or wrongly) assumed gains to the future from a supposed growing net GDP.[61] That being said, not all economists share this opinion as notable economist Frank Ramsey once described discounting as "ethically indefensible."[61]
One root of this controversy can be attributed to the discrepancies between the time scales environmentalists and corporations/governments view the world with. Environmental processes such as the carbonate-silicate cycle and Milankovitch cycles occur on timescales of thousands of years while economic processes, such as infrastructure investments, occur on time scales as short as thirty years. The difference between these two scales makes balancing both interests, sustainability and efficiency, incredibly difficult.[61]
Cost estimates
[edit]Several factors affect mitigation cost estimates. One is the baseline. This is a reference scenario that the alternative mitigation scenario is compared with. Others are the way costs are modelled, and assumptions about future government policy.[62]: 622 Cost estimates for mitigation for specific regions depend on the quantity of emissions allowed for that region in future, as well as the timing of interventions.[63]: 90
Mitigation costs will vary according to how and when emissions are cut. Early, well-planned action will minimize the costs.[64] Globally, the benefits of keeping warming under 2 °C exceed the costs,[65] which according to The Economist are affordable.[66]
Economists estimate the cost of climate change mitigation at between 1% and 2% of GDP.[67][68] While this is a large sum, it is still far less than the subsidies governments provide to the ailing fossil fuel industry. The International Monetary Fund estimated this at more than $5 trillion per year.[69][70]
Another estimate says that financial flows for climate mitigation and adaptation are going to be over $800 billion per year. These financial requirements are predicted to exceed $4 trillion per year by 2030.[71][72]
Globally, limiting warming to 2 °C may result in higher economic benefits than economic costs.[73]: 300 The economic repercussions of mitigation vary widely across regions and households, depending on policy design and level of international cooperation. Delayed global cooperation increases policy costs across regions, especially in those that are relatively carbon intensive at present. Pathways with uniform carbon values show higher mitigation costs in more carbon-intensive regions, in fossil-fuels exporting regions and in poorer regions. Aggregate quantifications expressed in GDP or monetary terms undervalue the economic effects on households in poorer countries. The actual effects on welfare and well-being are comparatively larger.[74]
Cost–benefit analysis may be unsuitable for analysing climate change mitigation as a whole. But it is still useful for analysing the difference between a 1.5 °C target and 2 °C.[67] One way of estimating the cost of reducing emissions is by considering the likely costs of potential technological and output changes. Policymakers can compare the marginal abatement costs of different methods to assess the cost and amount of possible abatement over time. The marginal abatement costs of the various measures will differ by country, by sector, and over time.[64]
Eco-tariffs on only imports contribute to reduced global export competitiveness and to deindustrialization.[75]Global costs
[edit]Mitigation cost estimates depend critically on the baseline (in this case, a reference scenario that the alternative scenario is compared with), the way costs are modelled, and assumptions about future government policy.[76]: 622 Macroeconomic costs in 2030 were estimated for multi-gas mitigation (reducing emissions of carbon dioxide and other GHGs, such as methane) as between a 3% decrease in global GDP to a small increase, relative to baseline.[4] This was for an emissions pathway consistent with atmospheric stabilization of GHGs between 445 and 710 ppm CO2-eq. In 2050, the estimated costs for stabilization between 710 and 445 ppm CO2-eq ranged between a 1% gain to a 5.5% decrease in global GDP, relative to baseline. These cost estimates were supported by a moderate amount of evidence and much agreement in the literature.[77]: 11, 18
Macroeconomic cost estimates were mostly based on models that assumed transparent markets, no transaction costs, and perfect implementation of cost-effective policy measures across all regions throughout the 21st century.[4]: 204 Relaxation of some or all these assumptions would lead to an appreciable increase in cost estimates. On the other hand, cost estimates could be reduced by allowing for accelerated technological learning, or the possible use of carbon tax/emission permit revenues to reform national tax systems.[77]: 8
In most of the assessed studies, costs rose for increasingly stringent stabilization targets. In scenarios that had high baseline emissions, mitigation costs were generally higher for comparable stabilization targets. In scenarios with low emissions baselines, mitigation costs were generally lower for comparable stabilization targets.
Regional costs
[edit]Several studies have estimated regional mitigation costs. The conclusions of these studies are as follows:[80]: 776
- Regional abatement costs are largely dependent on the assumed stabilization level and baseline scenario. The allocation of emission allowances/permits is also an important factor, but for most countries, is less important than the stabilization level.
- Other costs arise from changes in international trade. Fossil fuel-exporting regions are likely to be affected by losses in coal and oil exports compared to baseline, while some regions might experience increased bio-energy (energy derived from biomass) exports.
- Allocation schemes based on current emissions (i.e., where the most allowances/permits are given to the largest current polluters, and the fewest allowances are given to smallest current polluters) lead to welfare losses for developing countries, while allocation schemes based on a per capita convergence of emissions (i.e., where per capita emissions are equalized) lead to welfare gains for developing countries.
Cost sharing
[edit]Distributing emissions abatement costs
[edit]There have been different proposals on how to allocate responsibility for cutting emissions:[81]: 103
- Egalitarianism: this system interprets the problem as one where each person has equal rights to a global resource, i.e., polluting the atmosphere.
- Basic needs: this system would have emissions allocated according to basic needs, as defined according to a minimum level of consumption. Consumption above basic needs would require countries to buy more emission rights. From this viewpoint, developing countries would need to be at least as well off under an emissions control regime as they would be outside the regime.
- Proportionality and polluter-pays principle: Proportionality reflects the ancient Aristotelian principle that people should receive in proportion to what they put in, and pay in proportion to the damages they cause. This has a potential relationship with the "polluter-pays principle", which can be interpreted in a number of ways:
- Historical responsibilities: this asserts that allocation of emission rights should be based on patterns of past emissions. Two-thirds of the stock of GHGs in the atmosphere at present is due to the past actions of developed countries.[82]: 29
- Comparable burdens and ability to pay: with this approach, countries would reduce emissions based on comparable burdens and their ability to take on the costs of reduction. Ways to assess burdens include monetary costs per head of population, as well as other, more complex measures, like the UNDP's Human Development Index.
- Willingness to pay: with this approach, countries take on emission reductions based on their ability to pay along with how much they benefit[83] from reducing their emissions.
Specific proposals
[edit]- Equal per capita entitlements: this is the most widely cited method of distributing abatement costs, and is derived from egalitarianism.[81]: 106 This approach can be divided into two categories. In the first category, emissions are allocated according to national population. In the second category, emissions are allocated in a way that attempts to account for historical (cumulative) emissions.
- Status quo: with this approach, historical emissions are ignored, and current emission levels are taken as a status quo right to emit.[81]: 107 An analogy for this approach can be made with fisheries, which is a common, limited resource. The analogy would be with the atmosphere, which can be viewed as an exhaustible natural resource.[82]: 27 In international law, one state recognized the long-established use of another state's use of the fisheries resource. It was also recognized by the state that part of the other state's economy was dependent on that resource.
Economic barriers to addressing climate change mitigation
[edit]Economic components like the stock market underestimate or cannot value social benefits of climate change mitigation.[84] Climate change is largely an externality,[85][86][87] despite a limited recent internalization of impacts that previously were fully 'external' to the economy.[88]
Consumers can be and are affected by policies that relate to e.g. ethical consumer literacy,[89] the available choices they have, transportation policy,[90] product transparency policies,[91][92][93][94] and larger-order economic policies that for example facilitate large-scale shifts of jobs.[95][96] Such policies or measures are sometimes unpopular with the population. Therefore, they may be difficult for politicians to enact directly or help facilitate indirectly.
According to a study, "staying within a 1.5 °C carbon budget (50% probability) implies leaving almost 40% of 'developed reserves' of fossil fuels unextracted".[97] Climate policies-induced future lost financial profits from global stranded fossil-fuel assets would lead to major losses for freely managed wealth of investors in advanced economies in current economics.[98]
See also
[edit]References
[edit]- ^ "Energy Transition Investment Hit $500 Billion in 2020 – For First Time". BloombergNEF. (Bloomberg New Energy Finance). 19 January 2021. Archived from the original on 19 January 2021.
- ^ Catsaros, Oktavia (26 January 2023). "Global Low-Carbon Energy Technology Investment Surges Past $1 Trillion for the First Time". Figure 1: Bloomberg NEF (New Energy Finance). Archived from the original on 22 May 2023.
Defying supply chain disruptions and macroeconomic headwinds, 2022 energy transition investment jumped 31% to draw level with fossil fuels
{{cite news}}
: CS1 maint: location (link) - ^ "Global Clean Energy Investment Jumps 17%, Hits $1.8 Trillion in 2023, According to BloombergNEF Report". BNEF.com. Bloomberg NEF. 30 January 2024. Archived from the original on 28 June 2024.
Start years differ by sector but all sectors are present from 2020 onwards.
- ^ a b c Fisher, B.S.; et al. (2007). "Issues related to mitigation in the long term context.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press. Archived from the original on 16 November 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ "The global backlash against climate policies has begun". The Economist. ISSN 0013-0613. Retrieved 11 November 2023.
- ^ a b "What is a carbon price and why do we need one?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ "Understanding carbon pricing". Carbon Pricing Leadership Coalition. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ "Which is better: carbon tax or cap-and-trade?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Implementing a US carbon tax : challenges and debates. Parry, Ian W. H. (Ian William Holmes), 1965-, Morris, Adele Cecile, 1963-, Williams, Roberton C., 1972-. New York. 2015. ISBN 978-1-138-81415-8. OCLC 891001377.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) CS1 maint: others (link) - ^ "Pros and cons of a carbon tax » Yale Climate Connections". Yale Climate Connections. 20 July 2016. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Chen, Zi-yue; Nie, Pu-yan (1 December 2016). "Effects of carbon tax on social welfare: A case study of China". Applied Energy. 183: 1607–1615. Bibcode:2016ApEn..183.1607C. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.09.111. ISSN 0306-2619.
- ^ Irfan, Umair (17 May 2019). "Fossil fuels are underpriced by a whopping $5.2 trillion". Vox. Retrieved 23 November 2019.
- ^ a b "Cap and Trade: Key Terms Glossary" (PDF). Climate Change 101. Center for Climate and Energy Solutions. January 2011. Archived from the original (PDF) on 5 October 2017. Retrieved 27 October 2014.
- ^ "Which is better: carbon tax or cap-and-trade?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ a b Goulder, Lawrence; Schein, Andrew (August 2013). "Carbon Taxes vs. Cap and Trade: A Critical Review". NBER Working Paper Series. Cambridge, MA. doi:10.3386/w19338. S2CID 158104668.
- ^ Thomas Wiedmann; Manfred Lenzen; Lorenz T. Keyßer; Julia Steinberger (19 June 2020). "Scientists' warning on affluence". Nature Communications. 11 (1): 3107. Bibcode:2020NatCo..11.3107W. doi:10.1038/s41467-020-16941-y. PMC 7305220. PMID 32561753.
- ^ "Why GDP is no longer the most effective measure of economic success". www.worldfinance.com. Retrieved 17 September 2020.
- ^ Kapoor, Amit; Debroy, Bibek (4 October 2019). "GDP Is Not a Measure of Human Well-Being". Harvard Business Review. Retrieved 20 September 2020.
- ^ Hickel, Jason; Hallegatte, Stéphane (2021). "Can we live within environmental limits and still reduce poverty? Degrowth or decoupling?". Development Policy Review. 40. doi:10.1111/dpr.12584. ISSN 1467-7679. S2CID 239636388.
- ^ Landler, Mark; Sengupta, Somini (21 January 2020). "Trump and the Teenager: A Climate Showdown at Davos". The New York Times. Retrieved 20 September 2020.
- ^ "Skills for Green Jobs: A Global View" (PDF). Retrieved 8 November 2021.
- ^ van der Ree, Kees (1 June 2019). "Promoting Green Jobs: Decent Work in the Transition to Low-Carbon, Green Economies". International Development Policy | Revue internationale de politique de développement (11): 248–271. doi:10.4000/poldev.3107. ISSN 1663-9375. S2CID 197784487.
- ^ Hickel, Jason; Kallis, Giorgos; Jackson, Tim; O'Neill, Daniel W.; Schor, Juliet B.; Steinberger, Julia K.; et al. (12 December 2022). "Degrowth can work — here's how science can help". Nature. 612 (7940): 400–403. Bibcode:2022Natur.612..400H. doi:10.1038/d41586-022-04412-x. PMID 36510013. S2CID 254614532.
Researchers in ecological economics call for a different approach — degrowth. Wealthy economies should abandon growth of gross domestic product (GDP) as a goal, scale down destructive and unnecessary forms of production to reduce energy and material use, and focus economic activity around securing human needs and well-being.
- ^ Foster, John Bellamy (1 July 2023). "Planned Degrowth: Ecosocialism and Sustainable Human Development". Monthly Review. Retrieved 24 August 2023.
Degrowth, in this sense, is not aimed at austerity, but at finding a "prosperous way down" from our current extractivist, wasteful, ecologically unsustainable, maldeveloped, exploitative, and unequal, class-hierarchical world. Continued growth would occur in some areas of the economy, made possible by reductions elsewhere. Spending on fossil fuels, armaments, private jets, sport utility vehicles, second homes, and advertising would need to be cut in order to provide room for growth in such areas as regenerative agriculture, food production, decent housing, clean energy, accessible health care, universal education, community welfare, public transportation, digital connectivity, and other areas related to green production and social needs.
- ^ Borowy, Iris; Aillon, Jean-Louis (1 August 2017). "Sustainable health and degrowth: Health, health care and society beyond the growth paradigm". Social Theory & Health. 15 (3): 346–368. doi:10.1057/s41285-017-0032-7. ISSN 1477-822X. S2CID 152144759.
- ^ Aillon, J.; Cardito, M. (2020). "Health and Degrowth in times of Pandemic".
- ^ Missoni, Eduardo (1 July 2015). "Degrowth and health: local action should be linked to global policies and governance for health". Sustainability Science. 10 (3): 439–450. Bibcode:2015SuSc...10..439M. doi:10.1007/s11625-015-0300-1. ISSN 1862-4057. S2CID 55806403.
Volume and increase of spending in the health sector contribute to economic growth, but do not consistently relate with better health. Instead, unsatisfactory health trends, health systems' inefficiencies, and high costs are linked to the globalization of a growth society dominated by neoliberal economic ideas and policies of privatization, deregulation, and liberalization. A degrowth approach, understood as frame that connects diverse ideas, concepts, and proposals alternative to growth as a societal objective, can contribute to better health and a more efficient use of health systems.
- ^ Büchs, Milena; Koch, Max (1 January 2019). "Challenges for the degrowth transition: The debate about wellbeing". Futures. 105: 155–165. doi:10.1016/j.futures.2018.09.002. ISSN 0016-3287. S2CID 149731503.
The first part reviews the arguments that degrowth proponents have put forward on the ways in which degrowth can maintain or even improve wellbeing. It also outlines why the basic needs approach is most suitable for conceptualising wellbeing in a degrowth context. The second part considers additional challenges to maintaining or even improving current levels of wellbeing under degrowth
- ^ Kostakis, Vasilis; Latoufis, Kostas; Liarokapis, Minas; Bauwens, Michel (1 October 2018). "The convergence of digital commons with local manufacturing from a degrowth perspective: Two illustrative cases". Journal of Cleaner Production. 197: 1684–1693. Bibcode:2018JCPro.197.1684K. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.09.077. ISSN 0959-6526. S2CID 43975556.
A large part of the activity taking place under the CBPP umbrella presents a lot of similarities with the degrowth concept of unpaid work and decommodification (Nierling, 2012). The majority of "peers" engaged in commons-oriented projects are motivated by passion, communication, learning and enrichment (Benkler, 2006, 2011). Kostakis et al. (2015, 2016) have only theoretically and conceptually explored the contours of an emerging productive model that builds on the convergence of the digital commons of knowledge, software and design with local manufacturing technologies. They tentatively call it "design global, manufacture local"
- ^ Scarrow, Ryan (April 2018). "Work and degrowth". Nature Sustainability. 1 (4): 159. Bibcode:2018NatSu...1..159S. doi:10.1038/s41893-018-0057-5. ISSN 2398-9629. S2CID 149576398.
- ^ Haberl, Helmut; Wiedenhofer, Dominik; Virág, Doris; Kalt, Gerald; Plank, Barbara; Brockway, Paul; Fishman, Tomer; Hausknost, Daniel; Krausmann, Fridolin; Leon-Gruchalski, Bartholomäus; Mayer, Andreas; Pichler, Melanie; Schaffartzik, Anke; Sousa, Tânia; Streeck, Jan; Creutzig, Felix (10 June 2020). "A systematic review of the evidence on decoupling of GDP, resource use and GHG emissions, part II: synthesizing the insights". Environmental Research Letters. 15 (6): 065003. Bibcode:2020ERL....15f5003H. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ab842a. ISSN 1748-9326. S2CID 216453887.
- ^ Hickel, Jason (3 October 2021). "What does degrowth mean? A few points of clarification". Globalizations. 18 (7): 1105–1111. Bibcode:2021Glob...18.1105H. doi:10.1080/14747731.2020.1812222. ISSN 1474-7731. S2CID 221800076.
- ^ Millward-Hopkins, Joel; Steinberger, Julia K.; Rao, Narasimha D.; Oswald, Yannick (1 November 2020). "Providing decent living with minimum energy: A global scenario". Global Environmental Change. 65: 102168. Bibcode:2020GEC....6502168M. doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2020.102168. ISSN 0959-3780. S2CID 224977493.
- ^ "World Energy Investment 2023 / Overview and key findings". International Energy Agency (IEA). 25 May 2023. Archived from the original on 31 May 2023.
Global energy investment in clean energy and in fossil fuels, 2015-2023 (chart)
— From pages 8 and 12 of World Energy Investment 2023 (archive). - ^ "Top-down Climate Finance Needs". CPI. Retrieved 27 June 2024.
- ^ Kreibiehl, S., T. Yong Jung, S. Battiston, P. E. Carvajal, C. Clapp, D. Dasgupta, N. Dube, R. Jachnik, K. Morita, N. Samargandi, M. Williams, 2022: Investment and finance. In IPCC, 2022: Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [P.R. Shukla, J. Skea, R. Slade, A. Al Khourdajie, R. van Diemen, D. McCollum, M. Pathak, S. Some, P. Vyas, R. Fradera, M. Belkacemi, A. Hasija, G. Lisboa, S. Luz, J. Malley, (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA. doi:10.1017/9781009157926.017
- ^ OECD (2022), Aggregate trends of Climate Finance Provided and Mobilised by Developed Countries in 2013-2020, https://www.oecd.org/climate-change/finance-usd-100-billion-goal .
- ^ New, M., D. Reckien, D. Viner, C. Adler, S.-M. Cheong, C. Conde, A. Constable, E. Coughlan de Perez, A. Lammel, R. Mechler, B. Orlove, and W. Solecki, 2022: Chapter 17: Decision-Making Options for Managing Risk. In: Climate Change 2022: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [H.-O. Pörtner, D.C. Roberts, M. Tignor, E.S. Poloczanska, K. Mintenbeck, A. Alegría, M. Craig, S. Langsdorf, S. Löschke, V. Möller, A. Okem, B. Rama (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, pp. 2539–2654, doi:10.1017/9781009325844.026
- ^ "Global Landscape of Climate Finance 2023" (PDF). CPI.
- ^ United Nations Environment Programme (2023). Adaptation Gap Report 2023: Underfinanced. Underprepared. Inadequate investment and planning on climate adaptation leaves world exposed. Nairobi. https://doi . org/10.59117/20.500.11822/43796
- ^ a b c d e f g Markandya, A.; et al. (2001). "Costing Methodologies. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. pp. 474–476. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
- ^ "Chapter 2: Emissions trends and drivers" (PDF). Ipcc_Ar6_Wgiii. 2022. Archived from the original (PDF) on 4 April 2022. Retrieved 10 April 2022.
- ^ Toth, F.L.; et al. (2001). "Decision-making Frameworks". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. pp. 607–609. Archived from the original on 13 October 2012. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
- ^ "No Regrets: Circles of Climate Change Adaptation – Principles and Practices for Responding to Climate Change". Retrieved 20 May 2021.
- ^ Philander, S. George (2012). Encyclopedia of Global Warming & Climate Change. SAGE Publications, Inc. p. 1720. doi:10.4135/9781452218564. ISBN 978-1-4129-9261-9.
- ^ "AR6 wg3 ts" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 4 April 2022. Retrieved 4 April 2022.
- ^ a b IPCC (2007c). "Annex. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 819. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ "Coal exit benefits outweigh its costs — PIK Research Portal". www.pik-potsdam.de. Archived from the original on 24 March 2020. Retrieved 24 March 2020.
- ^ "The Sixth Carbon Budget Surface Transport" (PDF). UKCCC.
there is zero net cost to the economy of switching from cars to walking and cycling
- ^ a b John Weyant. (2017) Some Contributions of Integrated Assessment Models of Global Climate Change. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 11:1, 115-137
- ^ Halsnæs, K.; et al. (2007). "Framing issues". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 127. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ Arrow, K.J.; et al. (1996b). Intertemporal Equity, Discounting, and Economic Efficiency. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. (eds.)). This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: Prof. Joseph Stiglitz's web page at Columbia University. pp. 125–144. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8. Retrieved 11 February 2010.
- ^ Nordhaus, William (2014). "Estimates of the Social Cost of Carbon: Concepts and Results from the DICE-2013R Model and Alternative Approaches". Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists. 1: 273–312. doi:10.1086/676035. S2CID 155012348.
- ^ IPCC (2001a). "Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
- ^ Nordhaus, W. (2008) A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies Archived 25 May 2017 at the Wayback Machine Yale University Press pp. 10-11
- ^ Ackerman, F. (2007) Debating Climate Economics: The Stern Review vs. Its Critics Archived 3 October 2016 at the Wayback Machine Global Development and Environment Institute
- ^ Anthoff, D., R.S.J.Tol, and G.W.Yohe (2009), 'Discounting for Climate Change', Economics -- the Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 3, (2009-24), pp. 1-24.
- ^ U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) December 2010, Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses: Discounting Future Benefits and Costs
- ^ "The Use of Discount Rates" (PDF). European Commission - European Commission. Retrieved 24 August 2020.
- ^ Frederick, Shane; Loewenstein, George; O'Donoghue, Ted (June 2002). "Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review". Journal of Economic Literature. 40 (2): 351–401. doi:10.1257/002205102320161311. ISSN 0022-0515.
- ^ a b c Heal, G. M. (1997). Discounting and climate change. Columbia Business School, Columbia University. OCLC 760924527.
- ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 8 June 2011. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ IPCC, 2007: Technical Summary - Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Archived 2009-12-11 at the Wayback Machine [B. Metz, O.R. Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave, L.A. Meyer (eds)], Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, United States., XXX pp.
- ^ a b Stern, N. (2006). Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change: Part III: The Economics of Stabilisation. HM Treasury, London: http://hm-treasury.gov.uk/sternreview_index.htm
- ^ Sampedro, Jon; Smith, Steven J.; Arto, Iñaki; González-Eguino, Mikel; Markandya, Anil; Mulvaney, Kathleen M.; Pizarro-Irizar, Cristina; Van Dingenen, Rita (2020). "Health co-benefits and mitigation costs as per the Paris Agreement under different technological pathways for energy supply". Environment International. 136: 105513. Bibcode:2020EnInt.13605513S. doi:10.1016/j.envint.2020.105513. hdl:10810/44202. PMID 32006762. S2CID 211004787.
- ^ "The energy transition will be much cheaper than you think". The Economist. ISSN 0013-0613. Retrieved 16 November 2024.
- ^ a b "Can cost benefit analysis grasp the climate change nettle? And can we..." Oxford Martin School. Retrieved 11 November 2019.
- ^ Kotz, Mazimilian.; Levermann, Anders; Wenz, Leonie (17 April 2024). "The economic commitment of climate change". Nature. 628 (8008): 551–557. Bibcode:2024Natur.628..551K. doi:10.1038/s41586-024-07219-0. PMC 11023931. PMID 38632481.
- ^ "Below 1.5°C: a breakthrough roadmap to solve the climate crisis". One Earth. Retrieved 21 November 2022.
- ^ Teske, Sven, ed. (2 August 2019). Achieving the Paris Climate Agreement Goals: Global and Regional 100% Renewable Energy Scenarios with Non-energy GHG Pathways for +1.5°C and +2°C. Springer Science+Business Media. doi:10.1007/978-3-030-05843-2. ISBN 978-3030058425. S2CID 198078901 – via www.springer.com.
- ^ "The crucial intersection between gender and climate". European Investment Bank. Retrieved 29 December 2023.
- ^ Nations, United. "Finance & Justice". United Nations. Retrieved 29 December 2023.
- ^ IPCC (2022). Shukla, P.R.; Skea, J.; Slade, R.; Al Khourdajie, A.; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press. p. 300.: The global benefits of pathways limiting warming to 2°C (>67%) outweigh global mitigation costs over the 21st century, if aggregated economic impacts of climate change are at the moderate to high end of the assessed range, and a weight consistent with economic theory is given to economic impacts over the long term. This holds true even without accounting for benefits in other sustainable development dimensions or nonmarket damages from climate change (medium confidence).
- ^ IPCC (2022) Chapter 3: Mitigation pathways compatible with long-term goals in Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, United States
- ^ Evans, Stuart; Mehling, Michael A.; Ritz, Robert A.; Sammon, Paul (16 March 2021). "Border carbon adjustments and industrial competitiveness in a European Green Deal" (PDF). Climate Policy. 21 (3): 307–317. Bibcode:2021CliPo..21..307E. doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1856637. ISSN 1469-3062.
- ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 8 June 2011. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ a b IPCC (2007b). "Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ "Emissions Gap Report 2020 / Executive Summary" (PDF). UNEP.org. Fig. ES.8: United Nations Environment Programme. 2021. p. XV. Archived (PDF) from the original on 31 July 2021.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 maint: location (link) - ^ Climate Equality: a Climate for the 99% (PDF). Oxfam International. November 2023. Archived (PDF) from the original on 23 November 2023. Fig. ES.2, Fig. ES.3, Box 1.2.
- ^ Gupta, S.; et al. (2007), "Policies, Instruments and Co-operative Arrangements.", in B. Metz; et al. (eds.), Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A., archived from the original on 5 October 2018, retrieved 20 May 2009
- ^ a b c Banuri, T.; et al. (1996). Equity and Social Considerations. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J. P. Bruce et al. eds.). Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521568548. PDF version: IPCC website.
- ^ a b Goldemberg, J.; et al. (1996). Introduction: scope of the assessment. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J. P. Bruce et al. eds.). Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521568548. Web version: IPCC website.
- ^ Longo, Albert; Hoyos, David; Markandya, Anil (January 2011). "Willingness to Pay for Ancillary Benefits of Climate Change Mitigation". ResearchGate.
- ^ Tallarita, Roberto (9 August 2021). "The Limits of Portfolio Primacy". SSRN 3912977.
- ^ "Paying the Cost of Climate Change". Brookings. Retrieved 7 December 2023.
- ^ Mintz-Woo, Kian; Leroux, Justin (November 2021). "What do climate change winners owe, and to whom?". Economics & Philosophy. 37 (3): 462–483. doi:10.1017/S0266267120000449. hdl:10468/11123. ISSN 0266-2671.
- ^ Rosenbloom, Daniel; Markard, Jochen; Geels, Frank W.; Fuenfschilling, Lea (21 April 2020). "Why carbon pricing is not sufficient to mitigate climate change—and how "sustainability transition policy" can help". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 117 (16): 8664–8668. Bibcode:2020PNAS..117.8664R. doi:10.1073/pnas.2004093117. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 7183151. PMID 32269079.
- ^ Bartolomeo, Giovanni Di; Fard, Behnaz Minooei; Semmler, Willi (June 2023). "Greenhouse gases mitigation: global externalities and short-termism" (PDF). Environment and Development Economics. 28 (3): 230–241. doi:10.1017/S1355770X22000249. ISSN 1355-770X.
- ^ Papaoikonomou, Eleni; Ginieis, Matías; Alarcón, Amado Alarcón (15 November 2023). "The Problematics of Being an Ethical Consumer in the Marketplace: Unpacking the Concept of Ethical Consumer Literacy". Journal of Public Policy & Marketing. 43 (2): 133–150. doi:10.1177/07439156231202746. ISSN 0743-9156.
Instead of placing the responsibility on individual consumers, governments should increase ethical consumer literacy.
- ^ "AR6 Synthesis Report: Climate Change 2023 — IPCC". Retrieved 18 April 2023.
- ^ Hoang, Nguyen Tien; Kanemoto, Keiichiro (June 2021). "Mapping the deforestation footprint of nations reveals growing threat to tropical forests". Nature Ecology & Evolution. 5 (6): 845–853. Bibcode:2021NatEE...5..845H. doi:10.1038/s41559-021-01417-z. ISSN 2397-334X.
- ^ "Supermarket food could soon carry eco-labels, says study". 9 August 2022. Retrieved 7 December 2023.
- ^ Clark, Michael; Springmann, Marco; Rayner, Mike; Scarborough, Peter; Hill, Jason; Tilman, David; Macdiarmid, Jennie I.; Fanzo, Jessica; Bandy, Lauren; Harrington, Richard A. (16 August 2022). "Estimating the environmental impacts of 57,000 food products". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 119 (33): e2120584119. Bibcode:2022PNAS..11920584C. doi:10.1073/pnas.2120584119. hdl:2164/20863. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 9388151. PMID 35939701.
- ^ Kolcava, Dennis; Smith, E. Keith; Bernauer, Thomas (January 2023). "Cross-national public acceptance of sustainable global supply chain policy instruments". Nature Sustainability. 6 (1): 69–80. doi:10.1038/s41893-022-00984-8. ISSN 2398-9629.
- ^ "Skills for Green Jobs: A Global View" (PDF). Retrieved 8 November 2021.
- ^ van der Ree, Kees (1 June 2019). "Promoting Green Jobs: Decent Work in the Transition to Low-Carbon, Green Economies". International Development Policy | Revue internationale de politique de développement (11): 248–271. doi:10.4000/poldev.3107. ISSN 1663-9375. S2CID 197784487.
- ^ Trout, Kelly; Muttitt, Greg; Lafleur, Dimitri; Van de Graaf, Thijs; Mendelevitch, Roman; Mei, Lan; Meinshausen, Malte (17 May 2022). "Existing fossil fuel extraction would warm the world beyond 1.5 °C". Environmental Research Letters. 17 (6): 064010. Bibcode:2022ERL....17f4010T. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ac6228. hdl:1854/LU-8753303. ISSN 1748-9326. S2CID 248853320.
- News article: "Study warns nearly half of fossil fuel sites need to be shut down to avoid climate disaster". Interesting Engineering. Retrieved 22 June 2022.
- ^ Semieniuk, Gregor; Holden, Philip B.; Mercure, Jean-Francois; Salas, Pablo; Pollitt, Hector; Jobson, Katharine; Vercoulen, Pim; Chewpreecha, Unnada; Edwards, Neil R.; Viñuales, Jorge E. (June 2022). "Stranded fossil-fuel assets translate to major losses for investors in advanced economies". Nature Climate Change. 12 (6): 532–538. Bibcode:2022NatCC..12..532S. doi:10.1038/s41558-022-01356-y. hdl:11385/223918. ISSN 1758-6798. S2CID 249069181.
- News article: "People in US and UK face huge financial hit if fossil fuels lose value, study shows". The Guardian. 26 May 2022. Retrieved 22 June 2022.