Jump to content

Era of Stagnation

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Zastoy)

The "Era of Stagnation" (Russian: Пери́од засто́я, romanizedPeríod zastóya, or Эпо́ха засто́я Epókha zastóya) is a term coined by Mikhail Gorbachev in order to describe the negative way in which he viewed the economic, political, and social policies of the Soviet Union that began during the rule of Leonid Brezhnev (1964–1982) and continued under Yuri Andropov (1982–1984) and Konstantin Chernenko (1984–1985).[1][2] It is sometimes called the "Brezhnevian Stagnation" in English.

Terminology

[edit]

During the period of Brezhnev's leadership, the term "Era of Stagnation" was not used. Instead in Soviet ideology the term "period of developed socialism" (Russian: пери́од развито́го социали́зма) was used for the period that started in 1967. This Soviet concept was officially declared at the 24th Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union in 1971. It stemmed from the failure of Khrushchev's promise in 1961 of reaching communism in 20 years[3] and was a replacement for the concept "period of the extensive construction of communism" (Russian: период развёрнутого строительства коммунизма). It was in the 1980s that the Soviet leader Mikhail Gorbachev coined the term "Era of Stagnation" to describe the economic difficulties that developed when Leonid Brezhnev led the Soviet Union from 1964 to 1982.[4] Scholars have subsequently disagreed on the dates, significance and causes of the stagnation. Supporters of Gorbachev have criticised Brezhnev, and the Brezhnev administration in general, for being too conservative and failing to change with the times.[5]

History

[edit]

After the death of Soviet leader Joseph Stalin in 1953, a program of policy change was begun, later known as de-Stalinization. Nikita Khrushchev, who succeeded Stalin's brief successor Georgy Malenkov as Soviet leader, introduced relatively liberal reforms during the period known as the Khrushchev Thaw. This period also brought an economic increase that topped at 6%. The Manege Affair of 1962, during which Khrushchev publicly criticised an exhibition of Soviet art, led to the reassertion of Communist Party control over the arts and marked the beginning of the end of the Cultural Thaw.[6]

Brezhnev replaced Khrushchev as Soviet leader in 1964. The Brezhnev Era (1964–1982) began with high economic growth and soaring prosperity, but gradually significant problems in social, political, and economic areas accumulated. Social stagnation began following Brezhnev's rise to power, when he revoked several of Khrushchev's reforms and partially rehabilitated Stalinist policies. Some commentators regard the start of social stagnation as being the Sinyavsky–Daniel trial in 1966, in which two writers were convicted of anti-Soviet agitation and which marked the end of the Khrushchev Thaw.[7] Others place it at the time of the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia in 1968 that suppressed the Prague Spring.[8] The period's political stagnation is associated with the establishment of gerontocracy, which came into being as part of the policy of stability.

The majority of scholars set the starting year for economic stagnation at 1975, although some claim that it began as early as the 1960s. Industrial growth rates declined during the 1970s as heavy industry and the arms industry were prioritized while Soviet consumer goods were neglected.[9] The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1972 in retail prices was about 118 billion roubles.[10] Historians, scholars, and specialists are uncertain what caused the stagnation, with some arguing that the command economy suffered from systemic flaws that inhibited growth. Others have argued that the lack of reform, or the high expenditures on the military, led to stagnation.

Brezhnev has been criticised posthumously for doing too little to improve the economic situation. Throughout his rule, no major reforms were initiated and the few proposed reforms were either very modest or opposed by the majority of the Soviet leadership. The reform-minded Chairman of the Council of Ministers (Government), Alexei Kosygin, introduced two modest reforms in the 1970s after the failure of his more radical 1965 reform, and attempted to reverse the trend of declining growth. By the 1970s, Brezhnev had consolidated enough power to stop any "radical" reform-minded attempts by Kosygin.

After the death of Brezhnev in November 1982, Yuri Andropov succeeded him as Soviet leader. Brezhnev's legacy was a Soviet Union that was much less dynamic than it had been when he assumed power in 1964. During Andropov's short rule, modest reforms were introduced; he died little more than a year later in February 1984. Konstantin Chernenko, his successor, continued much of Andropov's policies. The economic problems that began under Brezhnev persisted into these short administrations and scholars still debate whether the reform policies that were followed improved the economic situation in the country.

The Era of Stagnation ended with Gorbachev's rise to power during which political and social life was democratised[11][12] even though the economy was still stagnating.[13] Under Gorbachev's leadership the Communist Party began efforts to accelerate economic development in 1985 through massive injections of finance into heavy industry (Uskoreniye). When these failed, the Communist Party restructured (perestroika) the Soviet economy and government by introducing quasi-capitalist (Khozraschyot) and democratic (demokratizatsiya) reforms. These were intended to re-energize the Soviet Union but inadvertently led to its dissolution in 1991.

Economy

[edit]

Analysis

[edit]

Robert Service, author of the History of Modern Russia: From Tsarism to the Twenty-first Century, claims that with mounting economic problems worker discipline decreased,[14] which the government could not counter effectively because of the full employment policy. According to Service, this policy led to government industries, such as factories, mines and offices, being staffed by undisciplined and unproductive personnel ultimately leading to a "work-shy workforce" among Soviet workers and administrators.[15] While the Soviet Union under Brezhnev had the "second greatest industrial capacity" after the United States, and produced more "steel, oil, pig-iron, cement and ... tractors" than any other country in the world,[16] Service treats the problems of agriculture during the Brezhnev era as proof of the need for de-collectivization.[17] In short, Service considers the Soviet economy to have become "static" during this time period,[18] and Brezhnev's policy of stability was a "recipe for political disaster".[19]

Richard Sakwa, author of the book The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Union: 1917–1991, takes a dimmer view of the Brezhnev era by claiming that growth rates fell "inexorably" from the 1950s until they stopped completely in the 1980s. His reasoning for this stagnation was the growing demand for unskilled workers resulted in a decline of productivity and labour discipline. Sakwa believes that stability itself led to stagnation and claimed that without strong leadership "Soviet socialism had a tendency to relapse into stagnation."[20]

According to Edwin Bacon and Mark Sandle, authors of Brezhnev Reconsidered, the economy under Brezhnev was as dynamic as the economy presided over by Nikita Khrushchev, but this dynamism had stalled by the time Yuri Andropov, and subsequently Konstantin Chernenko, became General Secretary.[21] Mark Harrison claims that the economic performance of the Brezhnev era has not been looked at objectively as analysis of the period sometimes used lower estimates.[22] Harrison further claims that in the period between 1928 and 1973 the Soviet economy grew in a phase that would surpass the United States "one day". During the international oil crisis, growth in the Soviet Union and the Eastern Bloc halted abruptly and stalled for a longer period than in the West[23] causing the economy to begin stagnating.[24] One explanation, according to Harrison, is that the Soviet economy could not sustain its extensive growth patterns.[25] Other explanations include: the lack of Soviet, and communist bloc, transparency with other nations hindering globalisation[26] and misinterpretation of a "permanent" post–World War II economic boom leading to faulty economic decisions.[27] He claims that the economic policies of Andropov, and Chernenko, had improved the economic situation in the country and Mikhail Gorbachev inherited a more dynamic and vibrant economy in a "pre-crisis situation" where the economy was still growing with low internal and external debts, compared to the economy that Andropov and Chernenko inherited.[28]

Archie Brown, author of The Rise and Fall of Communism, claims in his book that the term Era of Stagnation "was in many ways a fitting description, for this was a period of declining growth", but noted it could be misleading in non-economic spheres.[29] Brown states there were high growth rates in the mid-to-late 1960s (during the Eighth Five-Year Plan) claiming that the Soviet economy "enjoyed stronger growth in the second half of the 1960s than it ever did thereafter". The link between these growth rates and the Kosygin reform is, according to Brown, "tenuous",[30] but says that "From the point of view of communist rulers, the Brezhnev era was in many ways successful".[31] The Soviet Union's natural resources provided a strong economic foundation, which bore fruit during the 1973 oil crisis and "turned out to be an energy bonanza".[32] On the other hand, Brown states it was a sign of weakness that the Soviet Union grew so dependent on its natural resources, as it did in the 1970s.[31]

Scholars are generally unsure as to what effect the "Kosygin reform", named after its initiator Alexei Kosygin, had on economic growth

Philip Hanson, author of The Rise and Fall of the Soviet economy: an Economic History of the USSR from 1945, claims that the label stagnation is not "entirely unfair". Brezhnev, according to Hanson, did preside over a period of slowdown in economic growth, but claims that the era started with good growth that was at a higher rate than during the end of Khrushchev's rule. Economic slowdown began in 1973 "when even the official estimates began to show Soviet per capita production no longer closing the gap with the US." Before 1973, there was a reform period launched by Alexei Kosygin, which many believed would become as radical as those in the Socialist Republic of Czechoslovakia and the previous reform attempts in Hungary.[33] According to Hanson, many assumed that growth during the Brezhnev era did not stop but started to stagnate.[34] Not everything stagnated, as per capita consumption grew by 1.9% during the 1970s, which is a "highly respectable rate" of growth. Another point that Hanson makes is that, in contrast to the repressive policies of Joseph Stalin and instability-inducing policies of Khrushchev, the Brezhnev era was stable and a "period of (comparative) plenty".[35]

Robert Vincent Daniels in his book, Russia's Transformation: Snapshots of a Crumbling System, claimed that the hallmark of the Brezhnev era was the status quo, which in turn led to the development of a great paradox; "the contradictions of what it was and what it could be became obvious". Net growth, in excess of 50% and as high as two thirds, was primarily in the urban sector resulting in high population growth and urban growth higher than that of the United States. Industrial development continued to grow rapidly, and in certain sectors surpassed the United States.[36] As an example, coal production in the Soviet Union increased from 85 million metric tons in 1964 to 149 million metric tons in 1981 while in the United States it grew from 100 million to 130 million metric tons in the same period.[37] The Soviet Union became the largest exporter of petroleum in the world and by the end of the Tenth Five-Year Plan (1976–1981) the Soviet GNP "reached about 60% of the American level, and the net current investment was actually greater in absolute terms". The failure then, according to Daniels, was that the Soviet economy was not able to deliver in certain sectors; agriculture is a sector where this failure occurred. Throughout Soviet history, deficiencies in agriculture and consumer goods always existed. During Brezhnev's reign, the Soviet Union became the largest producer of wheat in the world but was unable to produce meat in sufficient quantities.[38] According to Daniels, the economy began to stagnate in 1975 rather than 1973 and that the following period contradicted the previous one "in almost every way".[39]

The research in second economy of the Soviet Union, pioneered by Gregory Grossman, indicated that during 1970s-1980s the effects of the central planning were progressively distorted due to the rapid growth of the shadow economy. It is suggested that failure to account for it by Gosplan contributed to the stagnation, and ultimately to the collapse of the Soviet economy.[40]

Causes

[edit]

One of the suggested causes of stagnation was the increased military expenditure over consumer goods and other economic spheres.[41] Andrei Sakharov, the veteran dissident, claimed in a 1980 letter to Brezhnev that the increasing expenditure on the armed forces was stalling economic growth.[42] David Michael Kotz and Fred Weir, authors of Revolution from Above: The Demise of the Soviet System, argue that militarisation cannot be the prime cause for the economic stagnation, as military spending had historically been high (17% of GNP in 1950) and had increased on par with economic growth without previously destabilising the economy.[citation needed]

During the Nixon Shock and the 1973 oil crisis, economic growth in the rest of the world plummeted but the Soviet hard currency earnings grew as a result of oil exports. Following the crisis, overall economic activity decreased markedly in the Soviet Union, the Western Bloc and Japan, but in the Soviet Union it was much more pronounced. Kotz and Weir argued that ultimately, economic stagnation in the Soviet Union could only have been caused by internal problems rather than external.[43]

Some Marxist–Leninist writers have argued that economic stagnation was a result of revisionism in Soviet economic policy during Khrushchev's leadership. According to authors like Harpal Brar, Khrushchev's de-Stalinization program was also used to implement economic reforms that would move the USSR away from central planning and towards market socialism.[44]

Summary

[edit]
Period Growth rates
GNP
(according to
the CIA)
NMP
(according to
G. I. Khanin)
NMP
(according to
the USSR)
1960–1965 4.8 4.4 6.5
1965–1970 4.9 4.1 7.7
1970–1975 3.0 3.2 5.7
1975–1980 1.9 1.0 4.2
1980–1985 1.8 0.6 3.5

One of the main causes for Khrushchev's dismissal from power was the relatively poor economic growth during the early 1960s. Overall economic growth was 6% from 1951 to 1955 but had fallen to 5.8% in the subsequent 5 years and to 5% from 1961 to 1965. Labour productivity, which had grown 4.7% from the 1950s to 1962, had declined to 4% by the early 1960s. Growth, capital out and investments were all showing signs of steady decline.[54] Another problem was Khrushchev's unrealistic promises such as committing to reach communism in 20 years, a near impossibility with the then-current economic indicators.[3] Ultimately, as a result of his failure to deliver on his promises and the problems engendered, Khrushchev was dismissed in October 1964[55] by a collective leadership led by Leonid Brezhnev and Alexei Kosygin. To counter Khrushchev's promise of reaching communism, the Soviet leadership created the term developed socialism, which meant that the Soviet Union had developed to a sufficiently advanced stage that the country would move "naturally" to communism (in an unspecified amount of time).[56]

Khrushchev's dismissal led to the establishment of a more conservative Politburo; Kosygin, Nikolai Podgorny and Andrei Kirilenko were the most liberal members, Brezhnev and Arvīds Pelše belonged to the moderate faction while Mikhail Suslov retained his leadership of the party's hardliners.[57] Kosygin and Brezhnev strongly disagreed over economic policy; Kosygin wanted to increase investments in consumer goods and light industry whereas Brezhnev wanted to increase investment in heavy industry, agriculture and defence.[58] In 1965, Kosygin introduced an economic reform, widely referred to as the "Kosygin reform", which aimed to reform the planned economy within a socialist framework. In a bid to improve the Soviet economy Kosygin copied some of the measures used in the Western Bloc, such as profit making,[59] which Brezhnev agreed to as the Soviet economy was entering a period of low growth.[60] Kosygin's reforms on agriculture gave considerable autonomy to the collective farms, giving them the right to the contents of private farming. As a result, during the Eighth Five-Year Plan (1966–1970), large-scale land reclamation programmes, construction of irrigation channels, and other measures, were enacted.[61][note 2] Overall, the reform failed and links to any high growth rates during the Eighth Five-Year Plan are considered to be "tenuous".[62]

The Brezhnev era, which had begun with high growth, began to stagnate some time in the early 1970s. Kosygin's "radical" reform attempts were halted in 1971 and his second reform was more modest. The second reform was halted because of the 1973 oil crisis, when an international increase in the price of oil prompted economic growth based on selling oil. Another reform was implemented in 1979 but this, too, failed as by this time the Soviet economy had become "addicted" to high oil prices.[61]

Opposition

[edit]

Acts of protest took place in reaction to the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia with protesters being dismissed from their jobs, beaten or arrested.[63] Eight protesters held a demonstration in Red Square in Moscow and were subsequently imprisoned.[64] A number of suspected dissidents had their homes and property searched[65] and a group of Moscow lawyers specialised in defending people charged with anti-Soviet activity.[66] Supporters of these meetings and demonstrations claimed that the arrests were illegal, because there is no criminality in the realization of the human right to obtain and distribute information. They asserted this right was part of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (1948)[67] and the final act of the Conference on Security and Co-operation in Europe (1975).[68]

Throughout the Brezhnev Era, artists producing work in accordance with "Soviet values" within the framework of socialist realism constituted a well-paid, elite group that enjoyed an easy life and high social status. Nevertheless, open and clandestine political opposition to the authorities by some Soviet scientists and artists (collectively known as "the dissidents") persisted from the Khrushchev Era. Prominent nuclear physicist Andrey Sakharov and Soviet Army General Pyotr Grigorenko were well-known representatives of this movement. When details of the Brezhnev government's efforts to suppress the speech of political dissidents came to light via the glasnost policies of the Gorbachev Era, many writers claimed to have been unaware of its widespread use.[69] Conversely, many members of the Soviet intelligentsia had systematically criticized the social and moral manifestations of the Stagnation without overtly challenging the authorities. Examples include writers Viktor Astafyev and Oles Honchar, playwright Grigory Gorin, and directors Eldar Ryazanov and Mark Zakharov.

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ Many economists argue that the net material product (NMP), the Soviet version of the gross national product (GNP), contained distortions and could not accurately determine a country's economic growth. Because of this, several specialists created GNP figures to estimate Soviet growth rates and to compare Soviet growth rates with the growth rates of capitalist countries.[46] Grigorii Khanin published his growth rates in the 1980s as a "translation" of NMP to GNP. His growth rates were (as seen above) much lower than the official figures, and lower than some Western estimates.[47] After the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991, Khanin's estimates led several agencies criticise the estimates made by the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA). Since then, the CIA has generally been regarded as having overestimated Soviet growth. In response to the criticism of CIA's work, a panel led by economist James R. Millar, was established to check out if this was in fact true. The panel concluded that the CIA were based on facts, and that Khanin's approach was methodologically naive, as it has not been possible for others to reproduce his results.[48] Growth figures for the Soviet economy vary widely (as seen below if compared to those at the table above):
    Eighth Five-Year Plan (1966–1970) Ninth Five-Year Plan (1971–1975)
    • GNP: 3.7%[49]
    • GNI: 5.1%[51]
    • Labour productivity: 6%[53]
    • Capital investments in agriculture: 27%[52]
    Tenth Five-Year Plan (1976–1980) Eleventh Five-Year Plan (1981–1985)
  2. ^ According to Soviet statistics, there were significant improvements made in the economy during the Eighth Five-Year Plan (1966–1970). The economy grew by 7.7% during the Eighth Five-Year Plan but slowed during the Ninth Five-Year Plan (1971–1975) and Tenth Five-Year Plan (1976–1981) when the economy grew by 5.7 and 4.2, respectively.[61]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ "The World Factbook". Cia.gov. Archived from the original on 9 January 2021. Retrieved 7 September 2015.
  2. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 1–2.
  3. ^ a b Dowlah & Elliott 1997, pp. 148–149.
  4. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 1.
  5. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 2.
  6. ^ Reid, Susan Emily (2005). "In the Name of the People: The Manege Affair Revisited". Kritika: Explorations in Russian and Eurasian History. 6 (4). Slavica Publishers: 673–716. doi:10.1353/kri.2005.0058. S2CID 159693587.
  7. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 143.
  8. ^ Bischof, Günter; Karner, Stefan; Ruggenthaler, Peter (2010). The Prague Spring and the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia in 1968. Rowman & Littlefield. p. 92. ISBN 978-0-7391-4304-9.
  9. ^ "1964-1982 – The Period of Stagnation". GlobalSecurity.org. Archived from the original on 28 July 2018. Retrieved 2 August 2017.
  10. ^ Gillula, James W. (1983). The Reconstructed 1972 Input-output Tables for Eight Soviet Republics (Manufactured goods sector was worth 118 billion roubles in 1972). U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Retrieved 2 January 2016.
  11. ^ Khazanov, Anatoly M. (1992). "Soviet Social Thought in the Period of Stagnation". Philosophy of the Social Sciences. 22 (2). SAGE Publications: 231–237. doi:10.1177/004839319202200205.
  12. ^ Grant, Ted (22 September 2006). "Russia, from Revolution to Counter-Revolution". In Defence of Marxism (Part 6). Archived from the original on 6 February 2009. Retrieved 31 December 2011.
  13. ^ Service 2009, p. 427.
  14. ^ Service 2009, p. 416.
  15. ^ Service 2009, p. 417.
  16. ^ Service 2009, p. 397.
  17. ^ Service 2009, p. 402.
  18. ^ Service 2009, p. 407.
  19. ^ Service 2009, p. 409.
  20. ^ Sakwa, Richard (1999). The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Union: 1917–1991. Routledge. p. 339. ISBN 0-415-12290-2.
  21. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 38.
  22. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 43–44.
  23. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 44–45.
  24. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 47.
  25. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 53.
  26. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 50–51.
  27. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 54.
  28. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 63.
  29. ^ Brown 2009, p. 398.
  30. ^ Brown 2009, p. 403.
  31. ^ a b Brown 2009, p. 415.
  32. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 415–416.
  33. ^ Hanson 2003, p. 98.
  34. ^ Hanson 2003, pp. 98–99.
  35. ^ Hanson 2003, p. 99.
  36. ^ Daniels 1998, p. 46.
  37. ^ Daniels 1998, pp. 47–48.
  38. ^ Daniels 1998, p. 47.
  39. ^ Daniels 1998, p. 49.
  40. ^ Vladimir G. Treml and Michael V. Alexeev, "The Second Economy And The Destabilizing Effect Of Its Growth On The State Economy In The Soviet Union : 1965-1989" Archived 25 October 2023 at the Wayback Machine, Berkeley-Duke Occasional Papers On The Second Economy In The Ussr, Paper No. 36, December 1993
  41. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 28.
  42. ^ Volkogonov, Dmitri; Shukman, Harold (1999). Autopsy for an Empire: The Seven Leaders Who Built the Soviet Regime. Simon & Schuster. p. 262. ISBN 978-0-684-87112-7.
  43. ^ Kotz, David Michael; Weir, Fred (1997). Revolution from Above: The Demise of the Soviet System. Routledge. p. 48. ISBN 978-0-415-14317-2.
  44. ^ Brar, Harpal (1992). Perestroika: The Complete Collapse of Revisionism. H. Brar. ISBN 1-874613-01-X.
  45. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 40.
  46. ^ Kotz & Weir 2007, p. 35.
  47. ^ Harrison, M. (1993). "Soviet economic growth since 1928: The alternative statistics of G. I. Khanin". Europe-Asia Studies. 45 (1): 141–167. doi:10.1080/09668139308412080.
  48. ^ Kotz & Weir 2007, p. 39.
  49. ^ a b c Kort, Michael (2010). The Soviet Colossus: History and Aftermath. M.E. Sharpe. p. 322. ISBN 978-0-7656-2387-4.
  50. ^ a b Bergson, Abram (1985). The Soviet economy: Toward the year 2000. Taylor & Francis. p. 192. ISBN 978-0-04-335053-9.
  51. ^ a b Pallot, Judith; Shaw, Denis (1981). Planning in the Soviet Union. Taylor & Francis. p. 51. ISBN 978-0-85664-571-6.
  52. ^ a b Wegren, Stephen (1998). Agriculture and the State in Soviet and Post-Soviet Russia. University of Pittsburgh Press. p. 252. ISBN 978-0-8229-8585-3.
  53. ^ a b Arnot, Bob (1988). Controlling Soviet Labour: Experimental Change from Brezhnev to Gorbachev. M.E. Sharpe. p. 67. ISBN 0-87332-470-6.
  54. ^ Dowlah & Elliott 1997, p. 148.
  55. ^ Dowlah & Elliott 1997, p. 149.
  56. ^ Dowlah & Elliott 1997, p. 146.
  57. ^ Law, David A. (1975). Russian Civilization. New York: Ardent Media. p. 221. ISBN 0-8422-0529-2.
  58. ^ Zemtsov, Ilya (1989). Chernenko: The Last Bolshevik: The Soviet Union on the Eve of Perestroika. Transaction Publishers. p. 86. ISBN 0-88738-260-6.
  59. ^ Moss, Walter (2005). A History of Russia: Since 1855. London: Anthem Press. p. 431. ISBN 978-1-84331-034-1.
  60. ^ Chauhan, Sharad (2004). Inside CIA: Lessons in Intelligence. APH Publishing. p. 207. ISBN 81-7648-660-4.
  61. ^ a b c "Советская экономика в эпоху Леонида Брежнева" [The Soviet economy in the era of Leonid Brezhnev]. RIA Novosti. 8 November 2010. Archived from the original on 2 April 2015. Retrieved 31 December 2011.
  62. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 58.
  63. ^ "Хроника Текущих Событий: выпуск 3" [Chronicle of Current Events: Issue 3]. memo.ru (in Russian). 30 August 1968. Archived from the original on 29 September 2012. Retrieved 2 January 2016.
  64. ^ Andrew Roth (9 August 2018). "Nearly half of Russians ignorant of 1968's Czechoslovakia invasion – poll". The Guardian. Archived from the original on 2 June 2024. Retrieved 20 August 2018.
  65. ^ "Хроника Текущих Событий: выпуск 4" [Chronicle of Current Events: Issue 4]. memo.ru (in Russian). 31 October 1968. Archived from the original on 4 February 2017. Retrieved 2 January 2016.
  66. ^ "Letter by Andropov to the Central Committee". 10 July 1970. Archived from the original on 11 March 2007.
  67. ^ Universal Declaration of Human Rights, resolution 217 A (III) Archived 8 November 2006 at the Wayback Machine, accepted 10 Dec. 1948.
  68. ^ "Conference On Security And Co-Operation In Europe Final Act". Helsinki: OSCE. 1 August 1975. Archived from the original on 23 April 2021. Retrieved 27 February 2016.
  69. ^ Sofia Kallistratova. We were not silent! – open letter to writer Chingiz Aitmatov, in Russian. С. В. Калистратова. Открытое письмо писателю Чингизу Айтматову Archived 2007-09-26 at the Wayback Machine, 5 мая 1988 г.

Bibliography

[edit]
[edit]
Preceded by History of Russia
History of the Soviet Union

14 October 1964 – 10 March 1985
Succeeded by