Jump to content

Donald G. Saari

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Donald Saari)
Donald G. Saari
BornMarch 1940 (age 84)
NationalityAmerican
Alma mater
Awards
Scientific career
Fields
Institutions
Thesis Singularities of the n-Body Problem of Celestial Mechanics  (1967)
Doctoral advisorHarry Pollard
Doctoral students

Donald Gene Saari (born March 1940) is an American mathematician, a Distinguished Professor of Mathematics and Economics and former director of the Institute for Mathematical Behavioral Sciences at the University of California, Irvine. His research interests include the n-body problem, the Borda count voting system, and application of mathematics to the social sciences.

Contributions

[edit]

Saari has been widely quoted as an expert in voting systems[1] and lottery odds.[2] He is opposed to the use of the Condorcet criterion in evaluating voting systems,[3] and among positional voting schemes he favors using the Borda count over plurality voting, because it reduces the frequency of paradoxical outcomes (which however cannot be avoided entirely in ranking systems because of Arrow's impossibility theorem).[4] For instance, as he has pointed out, plurality voting can lead to situations where the election outcome would remain unchanged if all voters' preferences were reversed; this cannot happen with the Borda count.[5] Saari has defined, as a measure of the inconsistency of a voting method, the number of different combinations of outcomes that would be possible for all subsets of a field of candidates. According to this measure, the Borda count is the least inconsistent possible positional voting scheme, while plurality voting is the most inconsistent.[3] However, other voting theorists such as Steven Brams, while agreeing with Saari that plurality voting is a bad system, disagree with his advocacy of the Borda count, because it is too easily manipulated by tactical voting.[4][6] Saari also applies similar methods to a different problem in political science, the apportionment of seats to electoral districts in proportion to their populations.[3] He has written several books on the mathematics of voting.[S94][S95a][S01a][S01b][S08]

In economics, Saari has shown that natural price mechanisms that set the rate of change of the price of a commodity proportional to its excess demand can lead to chaotic behavior rather than converging to an economic equilibrium, and has exhibited alternative price mechanisms that can be guaranteed to converge. However, as he also showed, such mechanisms require that the change in price be determined as a function of the whole system of prices and demands, rather than being reducible to a computation over pairs of commodities.[SS][S85][S95b]

In celestial mechanics, Saari's work on the n-body problem "revived the singularity theory" of Henri Poincaré and Paul Painlevé, and proved Littlewood's conjecture that the initial conditions leading to collisions have measure zero.[7] He also formulated the "Saari conjecture", that when a solution to the Newtonian n-body problem has an unchanging moment of inertia relative to its center of mass, its bodies must be in relative equilibrium.[8] More controversially, Saari has taken the position that anomalies in the rotation speeds of galaxies, discovered by Vera Rubin, can be explained by considering more carefully the pairwise gravitational interactions of individual stars instead of approximating the gravitational effects of a galaxy on a star by treating the rest of the galaxy as a continuous mass distribution (or, as Saari calls it, "star soup"). In support of this hypothesis, Saari showed that simplified mathematical models of galaxies as systems of large numbers of bodies arranged symmetrically on circular shells could be made to form central configurations that rotate as a rigid body rather than with the outer bodies rotating at the speed predicted by the total mass interior to them. According to his theories, neither dark matter nor modifications to the laws of gravitational force are needed to explain galactic rotation speeds. However, his results do not rule out the existence of dark matter, as they do not address other evidence for dark matter based on gravitational lenses and irregularities in the cosmic microwave background.[9] His works in this area include two more books.[SX][S05]

Overviewing his work in these diverse areas, Saari has argued that his contributions to them are strongly related. In his view, Arrow's impossibility theorem in voting theory, the failure of simple pricing mechanisms, and the failure of previous analysis to explain the speeds of galactic rotation stem from the same cause: a reductionist approach that divides a complex problem (a multi-candidate election, a market, or a rotating galaxy) into multiple simpler subproblems (two-candidate elections for the Condorcet criterion, two-commodity markets, or the interactions between individual stars and the aggregate mass of the rest of the galaxy) but, in the process, loses information about the initial problem making it impossible to combine the subproblem solutions into an accurate solution to the whole problem.[S15] Saari credits some of his research success to a strategy of mulling over research problems on long road trips, without access to pencil or paper.[10]

Saari is also known for having some discussion with Theodore J. Kaczynski in 1978, prior to the mail bombings that led to Kaczynski's 1996 arrest.[11]

Education and career

[edit]

Saari grew up in a Finnish American copper mining community in the Upper Peninsula of Michigan, the son of two labor organizers there. Frequently in trouble for talking in his classes, he spent his detention time in private mathematics lessons with a local algebra teacher, Bill Brotherton. He was accepted to an Ivy League university, but his family could only afford to send him to the local state university, Michigan Technological University, which gave him a full scholarship. He majored in mathematics there, his third choice after previously trying chemistry and electrical engineering.[12] While attending Michigan Tech, Saari joined the Beta Chapter of Theta Tau Professional Engineering Fraternity.

He received his Bachelor of Science in Mathematics in 1962 from Michigan Tech, and his Master of Science and PhD in Mathematics from Purdue University in 1964 and 1967, respectively.[13] At Purdue, he began working with his doctoral advisor, Harry Pollard, because of a shared interest in pedagogy, but soon picked up Pollard's interests in celestial mechanics and wrote his doctoral dissertation on the n-body problem.[12]

After taking a temporary position at Yale University, he was hired at Northwestern University by Ralph P. Boas Jr., who had also been doing similar work in celestial mechanics.[12] From 1968 to 2000, he served as assistant, associate, and full professor of mathematics at Northwestern, and eventually became Pancoe Professor of Mathematics there.[14] He was led to mathematical economics by discovering the high caliber of the economics students enrolling in his courses in functional analysis,[12] and added a second position as Professor of Economics.[14] He then moved to the University of California, Irvine at the invitation of R. Duncan Luce, who had founded the Institute for Mathematical Behavioral Sciences (IMBS) in the UCI School of Social Sciences in 1989.[12] At UC Irvine, he took over the directorship of the IMBS in 2003, and stepped down as director in 2017.[15] He is a trustee of the Mathematical Sciences Research Institute.[16]

He was editor in chief of the Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society from 1998 to 2005,[17] and published a book on the early history of the journal.[S03]

Awards and honors

[edit]

Selected publications

[edit]

Books

[edit]
S94.
Geometry of Voting, Studies in Economic Theory 3, Springer-Verlag, 1994.
  • Review of Geometry of Voting by Vincent Merlin (1995), Social Choice and Welfare 12 (1): 103–110, JSTOR 41106115.
  • Review of Geometry of Voting by Maurice Salles (1996), MR1297124.
S95a.
Basic Geometry of Voting, Springer-Verlag, 1995.
  • Review of Basic Geometry of Voting by Maurice Salles (1998), MR1410265.
S01a.
Chaotic Elections! A Mathematician Looks at Voting, American Mathematical Society, 2001.
S01b.
Decisions and Elections; Explaining the Unexpected, Cambridge University Press, 2001.
S05.
Collisions, Rings, and Other Newtonian N-Body Problems, American Mathematical Society, 2005.
S08.
Disposing Dictators, Demystifying Voting Paradoxes: Social Choice Analysis, Cambridge University Press, 2008.

Edited volumes

[edit]
SX.
Hamiltonian Dynamics and Celestial Mechanics (with Z. Xia), Contemporary Mathematics 198, American Mathematical Society, 1996.
S03.
The Way it Was: Mathematics From the Early Years of the Bulletin, American Mathematical Society, 2003.

Papers

[edit]
SS.
Saari, Donald G.; Simon, Carl P. (1978), "Effective price mechanisms" (PDF), Econometrica, 46 (5): 1097–1125, doi:10.2307/1911438, JSTOR 1911438.
  • Review of "Effective price mechanisms" by J. A. Rickard (1980), MR508687.
SU.
Saari, Donald G.; Urenko, John B. (1984), "Newton's method, circle maps, and chaotic motion", American Mathematical Monthly, 91 (1): 3–17, doi:10.2307/2322163, JSTOR 2322163
S85.
Saari, Donald G. (1985), "Iterative price mechanisms", Econometrica, 53 (5): 1117–1131, doi:10.2307/1911014, JSTOR 1911014.
  • Review of "Iterative price mechanisms" by Takayuki Nôno (1987), MR0809906.
S90.
Saari, Donald G. (1990), "A Visit to the Newtonian N-body problem via elementary complex variables", American Mathematical Monthly, 97 (2): 105–119, doi:10.2307/2323910, JSTOR 2323910
S95b.
Saari, Donald (1995), "Mathematical complexity of simple economics", Notices of the American Mathematical Society, 42 (2): 222–230.
  • Review of "Mathematical complexity of simple economics" by Dave Furth (1995), MR1311641.
SV.
Saari, Donald G.; Valognes, Fabrice (1998), "Geometry, voting, and paradoxes", Mathematics Magazine, 71 (4): 243–259, doi:10.2307/2690696, JSTOR 2690696
S15.
Saari, Donald G. (2015), "From Arrow's Theorem to 'Dark Matter'", British Journal of Political Science, 46 (1): 1–9, doi:10.1017/s000712341500023x, S2CID 154799988

References

[edit]
  1. ^ One Person, One Vote May Not Be The Fairest Of Them All, National Public Radio, October 14, 1995.
    Craven, Jo (November 1, 1998), "In Some Elections, The 'Bullet' Rules: Tactic Has Voters Skipping 2nd Choice", The Washington Post, archived from the original on April 24, 2017, retrieved April 23, 2017.
    "Has there been any progress in developing fairer ways for people to vote in elections?", Questions and Answers, Scientific American, October 1999, archived from the original on 2010-06-30, retrieved 2017-04-23.
    Mackenzie, Dana (November 1, 2000), "May The Best Man Lose", Discover Magazine.
    Guterman, Lila (November 3, 2000), "When Votes Don't Add Up", The Chronicle of Higher Education.
    Klarreich, Erica (November 2, 2002), "Election selection: are we using the worst voting procedure?", Science News, vol. 162, no. 18, pp. 280–282, doi:10.2307/4014063, JSTOR 4014063.
    Begley, Sharon (March 14, 2003), "How Beef-Hungry Voters Can Get Tofu for President", The Wall Street Journal.
    Cooper, Michael (July 27, 2003), "How to Vote? Let Us Count the Ways", The New York Times.
    Hoffman, Jascha (August 24, 2003), "Are All Elections Chaotic?", Boston Globe.
    Begley, Sharon (January 26, 2008), "When Math Warps Elections", Newsweek
    Schneider, Max (October 22, 2008), Voter Turnout Low, Apathy High Among Youngest Age Bracket, CBS News.
    Uninformed 'vital for democracy', BBC News, December 16, 2011.
  2. ^ "A Dow oddity beats the odds", Chicago Sun-Times, November 6, 1998.
    "Odds UCI math expert says chances of winning California Super Lotto are super low", Orange County Register, June 23, 2001.
  3. ^ a b c See Vincent Merlin's review of Geometry of Voting.[S94]
  4. ^ a b Peterson, Ivars (October 1998), "How to Fix an Election", Mathtrek, Science News, archived from the original on April 23, 2004.
    Peterson, Ivars (March 12, 2008), "Spoil-Proofing Elections", Mathtrek, Science News.
  5. ^ Peterson, Ivars (October 2003), "Election Reversals", Mathtrek, Science News.
  6. ^ Gilbert, Curtis (September 24, 2009), IRV advocates fire back at math prof., Minnesota Public Radio.
  7. ^ a b Chenciner, Alain; Cushman, Richard; Robinson, Clark; Xia, Zhihong Jeff (2002), Celestial Mechanics: Dedicated to Donald Saari for his 60th Birthday, Contemporary Mathematics, vol. 292, Providence, RI: American Mathematical Society, doi:10.1090/conm/292, ISBN 0-8218-2902-5, MR 1885140. Proceedings of an International Conference on Celestial Mechanics December 15–19, 1999 Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois. Preface, pp. ix–x.
  8. ^ Diacu, Florin; Fujiwara, Toshiaki; Pérez-Chavela, Ernesto; Santoprete, Manuele (2008), "Saari's homographic conjecture of the three-body problem", Transactions of the American Mathematical Society, 360 (12): 6447–6473, arXiv:0909.4991, doi:10.1090/S0002-9947-08-04517-0, ISSN 0002-9947, S2CID 16695757
  9. ^ Mackenzie, Dana (September 2013), "Rethinking "Star Soup"" (PDF), SIAM News, vol. 46, no. 7, archived from the original (PDF) on 2014-07-07, retrieved 2017-04-21
  10. ^ Robbins, Gary (October 30, 2006), "Scientists share insight on inspiration", Orange County Register.
  11. ^ Golab, Art (May 1, 1996), "NU Prof: Kaczynski Vowed to 'Get Even'", Chicago Sun-Times, archived from the original on April 24, 2017.
    Walsh, Edward (May 2, 1996), "Teacher May Have Met Kaczynski in '78; Man Trying to Get Paper Published Was Rebuffed and Angry, He Says", The Washington Post.
  12. ^ a b c d e Haunsperger, Deanna (2005), "Saari, with no Apologies" (PDF), College Mathematics Journal, 36 (2): 90–100, doi:10.2307/30044831, JSTOR 30044831. Reprinted in Albers, Donald J.; Alexanderson, Gerald L. (2011), Fascinating Mathematical People: interviews and memoirs, Princeton University Press, pp. 240–253, ISBN 978-0-691-14829-8.
  13. ^ Donald G. Saari at the Mathematics Genealogy Project
  14. ^ a b c Faculty profile, University of California, Irvine, retrieved 2017-04-22.
  15. ^ IMBS Faculty, Institute for Mathematical Behavioral Sciences, UC Irvine, retrieved 2018-12-26.
  16. ^ "Company Overview of Mathematical Sciences Research Institute, Donald Saari Ph.D., Trustee", bloomberg.com, 14 July 2023
  17. ^ Past Editorial Board Members, Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society, retrieved 2017-04-20.
  18. ^ "UCI scholar in science academy", Orange County Register, May 2, 2001.
  19. ^ "UCI professors efforts rewarded: Carew, Saari, Samueli and Wallace named Fellows of American Academy of Arts and Sciences for contributions to disciplines", Orange County Register, May 16, 2004.
    American Academy Announces 2004 Fellows and Foreign Honorary Members, American Academy of Arts and Sciences, April 30, 2004, retrieved 2017-04-22.
  20. ^ PIMS Distinguished Chair at the University of Victoria: Donald G. Saari, Pacific Institute for the Mathematical Sciences, archived from the original on January 2, 2007
  21. ^ Suomalaisen Tiedeakatemian ulkomaiset jäsenet [External members] (in Finnish), Finnish Academy of Science and Letters, retrieved 2017-04-22.
  22. ^ SIAM Fellows, Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, retrieved 2017-04-22.
  23. ^ List of Fellows, American Mathematical Society, retrieved 2013-07-11.
  24. ^ Saari elected to Russian Academy of Sciences, UC Irvine School of Social Sciences, December 3, 2018
  25. ^ "(9177) Donsaari", Minor Planet Center, retrieved 20 February 2020; "MPC/MPO/MPS Archive", Minor Planet Center, retrieved 20 February 2020
[edit]